PhD Chapter - better safe than sorry - paper review
Posted by: admin 3 years, 2 months ago
(Comments)
This time I would like to take a couple of important notes from my review chapter about being better safe than sorry.
The full page of this chapter can be found here: Link to the article
From the abstract to the introduction
Intro
- In particular, the notion of risk that lies at the heart of the Basel framework is still blind to extreme events. Climate risk and pandemic risk fall into this category.
- We offer avenues for reforming macroprudential regulation in a way that would allow us to take those risks into account.
- out why current banking regulation is not adequate to face risks whose origin is grounded outside financial markets – as is the case for both the pandemic and the climate risks
What missing from macroprudential policy
- Such an approach proved irrelevant once the crisis struck
- Prior to the crisis, the common belief was indeed that the combination between microprudential policies focusing on the soundness of financial institutions and monetary policies keeping inflation low was sufficient to ensure financial stability.
- for instance expressed by the G20, has therefore been the catalyst for the adoption of macroprudential policies whose purpose is to stabilize the monetary and financial system at the macro level
- Where the main objective being to contain the systemic risk.
How macroprudential work
- These latter aim at protecting the economy from systemic risk in its two dimensions (Borio, 2003): through time (temporal dimension), and at every moment (cross-sectional dimension).
- systemic risk indeed materializes through the pro- cyclicality of economic behaviors; and, on the other hand, it can spread thanks to the interconnections between financial institutions and the concentration of risk at a given point in time.
The main MP instruments
- he main macroprudential instruments are the following (Cerutti et al., 2017):
- countercyclical capital buffer,
- leverage ratio for banks,
- dynamic provisioning rules,
- caps on loan-to-value or debt-to-income ratios,
- limits on foreign currency loans,
- limits on risk concentration and capital surcharges for systemically important banking institutions.
The weakness of MP, from time perspective
- it remains focused on banks alone, even though the non-bank financial intermediation (NBFI) – which mainly comprises pension funds, insurance corporations and other financial intermediaries – has grown faster than the banking sector in the last 10 years. Indeed, the financial assets of the NBFI sector amounted to $200.2 trillion in 2019, accounting for nearly half of the global financial system, up from 42% in 2008 (Financial Stability Board, 2020).
- These countercyclical rules also seek to face the well-known paradox according to which any balance sheet item that serves as a shock absorber (liquid assets and/or capital) against adverse and unpredictable shocks ceases to fulfil this function as soon as regulatory pressure – through the definition of minimum requirements – is put on it. Only capital exceeding those minimum requirements constitutes a natural absorber of unanticipated losses. Indeed, when capital strictly reaches minimum requirements, additional losses deplete regulatory capital and induce credit rationing or other procyclical balance sheet adjustments such as fire sales.
- From shock absorbers, regulatory minima consequently become shock amplifiers. From a macroprudential perspective, the countercyclicality of prudential rules contradicts the invariance over time of liquidity and capital ratios (Kleinnijenhuis et al., 2020)
The weakness of MP from cross dimensional
- The imposition of capital surcharges for global systemically important banks (G- SIBs) is a flagship measure.
- The philosophy of this measure was jointly developed by the Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee in 2011 and was adjusted in 2013. The idea is that each G-SIB is assigned a composite score based on a set of five categories of quantitative indicators meant to indicate how systemic those banks are (size, interdependence, substitutability, cross-border activ- ities, complexity).
- Scores are then associated with additional capital requirements: the higher the score, the higher the amount of capital required. There are 5 tranches ranging from a 1% capital surcharge to a 3.5%. The last tranche is deliberately let empty, the purpose being to dissuade banks from becoming “too systemic”, hence the idea of a stigma associated with the simple fact of being in this last tranche.
- Indeed, when market participants are all subject to a value-at-risk constraint, risk becomes endogenous so that the procyclicality of banks’ behaviors increases (Danielsson et al., 2009).
- The unconditional support given to the financial system, notably through unconventional monetary policies, has led to a postponement of the recognition that market logic alone cannot constitute the cornerstone of regulation guaranteeing financial stability.
Why we need to focus on unpredicted risk or systemic risk
- The revival of the theme of market value in recent years, whether through market discipline as defined by the prudential corpus or fair value as defined by accounting standards (IFRS and US GAAP), paradoxically illustrates a reinforced confidence in the proper functioning of the market, while the swelling of central banks' balance sheets testifies to its malfunctioning.
- he Covid 19 crisis and the climate crisis are, as such, of a completely different nature. Indeed, they have their origin in processes which are, by their very nature, external to the functioning of financial markets.
- The main lesson is the need for a re-embedding of finance in socio-economic realities.
The discussion
- As it has been implemented in the aftermath of the 2007-08 crisis, macroprudential policy does not radically renew the foundations of pre-crisis banking regulation (Baker, 2013). In fact, the macroprudential instruments presented in the introduction appear more as extensions added to a regulatory corpus whose general intention remains microprudential, than as real breakthroughs.
- The main instrument of prudential regulation still consists in a risk-weighted capital ratio
- The problem of this ratio is that its computation is based on a definition of risk that does not allow to capture either fat-tailed risks and/or risks with no historical record, which are precisely great sources of systemic risk.
- “[…] traditional approaches to risk management consisting in extrapolating historical data based on assumptions of normal distributions are largely irrelevant to assess future climate-related risks. Indeed, both physical and transition risks are charac- terised by deep uncertainty, nonlinearity and fat-tailed distributions.” (Bolton et al., 2020, p. 10).
- Risk can then be measured as the volatility of these prices and estimated using value-at-risk models.
- banks. Indeed, with Solvency 2, insurance companies have to comply with capital requirements whose computation is based on the same philosophy as that on which rests Basel 3. More precisely, under Solvency 2, the Solvency Capital Requirement (SCR) is meant to absorb one-year expected losses in 99.5% of cases.
- This is problematic for at least two reasons. On the one hand, it extends to other financial institutions the risk management methods that have already shown their limits in the case of banks (Dan- ıelsson et al., 2004 ́ ). On the other hand, the application to insurance companies of rules similar to those that banks must comply with may lead to an excessive homogenization of financial behaviors, whose impact on financial stability could be potentially very negative (Wagner, 2008, 2010).
- asset. In this case, according to the three-level definition of fair value proposed by IFRS 13, fair value is estimated using a model, either based on public information (Level 2 fair value) or on the basis of information privately held by the company that holds the asset (Level 3 fair value).
- As already indicated, such a method entirely rests on the well-functioning of financial markets and proves to be much more difficult to implement in times of crisis.1
- Market discipline is indeed by nature a microprudential instrument (Stephanou, 2010). The idea behind market discipline is that prices have an informative and incentive power capable of driving banks, and more generally financial institutions, to adopt the right behaviors in terms of risk management.
- of risk that remains deeply linked to the well-functioning of financial markets.
- liquidity risk and systemic risk, it remains blind to all risks whose origin lies outside the market. T
- Covid crisis highlights the extent to which risk can, in a hyper-connected world and, moreover, at the verge of a climate crisis, mate- rialize outside the market.
- 3.1. From this perspective, the Covid crisis could act as a “dress rehearsal” and as such inspire the future structuring of macroprudential policy to prevent and mitigate climate-related financial risk. W
- The constitution of a shadow banking system, in which banking activities are mingled with financial activities, bears witness to this complexification. Such a complexification of banking and financial activities harms any attempt to regulate them. Indeed, the ever-increasing possibilities of escaping regulatory constraints, either because of regulatory arbitrage (Carruthers and Lamoreaux, 2016), or because of the complexity associated with the implementation of rules which leaves great room to “manipulate” regulatory ratios (Mariathasan and Merrouche, 2014), offers banks an unquestionable advantage over their regulator.
- In the light of the pandemic and climate crises: paths to a reinvention of macroprudential policy
Rethingking the macroprudential policy
- carries. It is indeed the voluntary slowing down of the economy to fight the pandemic that induces a rise in global risks in the financial sphere and not the endogenous risk that characterizes its functioning. From this point of view, the financial side of this crisis is totally different from that of the 2007-08 crisis
- onary pressures on the economy. They do not stem from the credit drifts and bubbles that they feed, nor do they stem from the illiquidity of the balance sheets of financial intermediaries or the concentration of financial risks. However, these are aggravating factors that are pushing for the consolidation of certain developments that are already well under way in macroprudential policy.
- the health crisis reinforces the pivotal role of central banks on financial stability issues and illustrates the interde- pendence between global financial risk management and risk prevention.
- The non-directly observable nature of macroprudential policy successes (financial cycle smoothing and financial crisis avoided) and the time lag between its immediate costs and its more difficult-to-measure and time-displaced benefits are among the notable difficulties facing its imple- mentation. T
- There is thus a “bias to inaction” specific to macroprudential policy (Houben et al., 2014). This form of temporal incoherence is further rein- forced in policies aimed at protecting the financial system from the systemic risks generated by the transition to a low-carbon economy, i.e. in the design and implementation of “green” or “climate” macroprudential policy. This is the famous tragedy of the horizon popularized by Marc Carney (2015).
- The “inaction bias” inherent in macroprudential policy is thus exacerbated in the case of climate macroprudential policy. The temptation to wait for a better analytical understanding and appreciation of climate risks and their dynamics leads to inaction.
- he simple recognition of the consensual scientific knowledge – carried by the IPCC (2014) – on the “material” effects of global warming, on the hysteresis bifurcations characterizing the tipping points and the irreversible changes in the climate system that they induce, even if our knowledge on the “conversion” of these into financial risks is very insufficient, should lead to the application of the precautionary principle.
Decision making under radical uncertainty
- Taking seriously the fact that we live in a world of radical uncertainty must lead to an equally radical transformation in the methods of economic and financial policy decision-making.
- In particular, the risk of catastrophic damage associated with a very low probability of occurrence – but with a considerable and irreversible impact – argues for a very ambitious transition to a low-carbon economy implemented as soon as possible (Weitzman, 2009).
- This recommendation, which is guided by the “generalized precautionary prin- ciple”, is hampered by the “tragedy of the horizon” (Carney, 2015) that paralyzes political decision-makers
- Consequently, collective action must be shaped by an ethical principle that integrates the well-being of future generations (Aglietta and Arrondel, 2019).
- When risk theory is no longer able to guide the actions of governments, central banks and regulators, an approach based on “enlightened catastrophism” can take over. It must result in the implementation of a generalized precautionary principle in the structuring of public policies and thus of macroprudential policy
- This is the paradox of “enlightened catastrophism”, which bears a similarity to the figure of the murderous judge who murders criminals before they commit their crimes. In doing so, the crimes do not exist and therefore the motivation for action does not exist either
- The usual partition between the time dimension (procyclicality) and the cross-sectional dimension of systemic risk (common exposures and interconnections) is irrelevant for preventing climate-related systemic financial risks.
- We do not observe a carbon cycle that could be defined as a succession of periods of overfinancing of industries with high greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and periods of contraction/correction of these drifts to which would correspond a cyclicity of GHG emissions. Carbon emissions have been steadily increasing and accelerating since the end of the Second World War due to “carbon lock-in” (Unruh, 2000).
- This “carbon lock-in” reflects the dependence on the path of Techno-Institutional Complexes based on fossil fuels. Conversely, the cross-sectional dimension of systemic risk must be central to the structuring of a “climate” macroprudential policy. This part of financial stability policy focuses on the interrelationships between different markets and between different financial institutions to account for common exposures, risk concentration, and credit re- lationships at a given point in time. I
- transition risk must be understood through cascades of failures due to the upstream and downstream interdependencies of the fossil fuel extraction and consumption industries, it is indeed the cross-sectional dimension of systemic risk that is relevant for structuring a “climate” macroprudential policy.
- he implementation of IFRS 9 in January 2018 could go against the objective of such policy since IFRS 9 mainly prescribes to resort to fair value to account for financial assets, which is known to deter financial institutions from investing in long-term assets (Le Quang, 2021; O'Hara, 1993).
- Fair value accounting thus incentivizes banks to focus on short-term assets and could impede the financing of the transition towards a greener economy.
Rethinking instruments
- I. Two options are possible: reducing capital constraints for “green” financing or increasing them for “brown” financing.
- First option It would consist in reducing the capital requirements of banks for the “green” financing they provide by reducing the risk weightings in the calculation of the denominator of the capital ratio. In other words, projects considered as “green” would be financed with more leverage and therefore less capital.
- A second optionalso integrates the non-measurable nature of climate-related financial risks, pleads for sectoral leverage ratios to supplement the brown penalizing factor by limiting excessive debt on asset classes backed by carbon-intensive sectors (D'Orazio and Popoyan, 2019) and therefore presenting a greater stranding risk.
- Basel 3 introduces, within Pillar 1, a leverage ratio that requires banks to finance at least 3% of their assets, regardless of the associated risk, with equity.
- stranding. The leverage ratio is more transparent and easier to determine than the risk-weighted capital ratio and thus limits the risk of undercapitalization due to the adoption of opportunistic behaviors by banks (Mariathasan and Merrouche, 2014).
- Sectoral capital requirements (SCR) are already part of existing macroprudential instruments. By requiring additional capital to cover exposures to a given sector, they are designed to complement the countercyclical capital cushion.
- The objective is to improve the resilience of banks to excessive growth in debt in the targeted sector and to provide incentives for banks to reduce their exposure to that sector
- An instrument to restrict the concentration of exposures to the same type of counterparty could also be considered. This prudential instrument exists and aims to limit the maximum possible losses in the event of default by a counterparty or a group
- The activation of the systemic risk buffer (SRB) would also be a possible protection against climate related financial risks. Defined in Article 133 of the Capital Requirement Directive IV (CRD IV), the SRB “aims at preventing or mitigating systemic risks of a ‘long-term non-cyclical’ nature which could disrupt the financial system and have serious negative consequences on the real economy of a given Member State”. T
- Since insurance undertakings also finance fossil fuel companies and their activities via equity and corporate bond investments, they should be included within the scope of the “climate” macroprudential policy that is here considered.
4.4. For an holistic approach of financial regulation
- As implemented following the 2007-08 crisis, macroprudential policy focuses exclusively on banks. This narrow perspective con- tradicts the growing importance taken by non-bank intermediation especially since the financial crisis (Financial Stability Board, 2020). This limited scope is a major weakness because global financial risks could be generated and amplified by non-bank financial in- termediaries.
- risk. According to the NGFS technical report (2021), the question of the “climate mandate” of central banks is now considered as both legitimate and necessary.
- This climate mandate may translate into a collateral policy where “green” collateral would be favored and “brown” collateral penalized. Such a penalization could either take the form of a limitation of the assets accepted as collateral or that of a haircut policy applied to “brown” collateral. S
- Tags:
- phdchapter
Kenapa sekolah PhD butuh waktu lama!?
Recent newsKali ini kita akan bahas kenapa sekolah PhD itu lama! Tanpa panjang lebar, berikut cara ngeles gw! Maksudnya berikut alasannya! Hope its relate with you!
read more3 days, 9 hours ago
Using Vertex AI for zero one and two three AI prediction
Recent newsHere is my documentation after learning the introduction of AI in courserERA.
read more2 weeks, 6 days ago
Neural network with API for pre-trained API
Recent newsOverview
The Cloud Natural Language API lets you extract entities from text, perform sentiment and syntactic analysis, and classify text into categories.
read more3 weeks, 1 day ago
what is null result
Recent newsNull result in economic is when the output does not supporting your hypothesis
read more3 weeks, 3 days ago
3 weeks, 3 days ago
Fixing the issue in assumption of OLS step by step or one by one
Recent newsHi, I want to raise the issue related to know whether your OLS is ok or not.
read more1 month, 2 weeks ago
Meaning of 45 degree in economics chart
Recent newsThe **45-degree line** in economics and geometry refers to a line where the values on the x-axis and y-axis are equal at every point. It typically has a slope of 1, meaning that for every unit increase along the horizontal axis (x), there is an equal unit increase along the vertical axis (y). Here are a couple of contexts where the 45-degree line is significant:
read more2 months, 3 weeks ago
Collaboratively administrate empowered markets via plug-and-play networks. Dynamically procrastinate B2C users after installed base benefits. Dramatically visualize customer directed convergence without
Comments